JiscMail Logo
Email discussion lists for the UK Education and Research communities

Help for ENVIROETHICS Archives


ENVIROETHICS Archives

ENVIROETHICS Archives


enviroethics@JISCMAIL.AC.UK


View:

Message:

[

First

|

Previous

|

Next

|

Last

]

By Topic:

[

First

|

Previous

|

Next

|

Last

]

By Author:

[

First

|

Previous

|

Next

|

Last

]

Font:

Proportional Font

LISTSERV Archives

LISTSERV Archives

ENVIROETHICS Home

ENVIROETHICS Home

ENVIROETHICS  2002

ENVIROETHICS 2002

Options

Subscribe or Unsubscribe

Subscribe or Unsubscribe

Log In

Log In

Get Password

Get Password

Subject:

Re: Lomborg, was Re: Patrick Moore

From:

Jim Tantillo <[log in to unmask]>

Reply-To:

Discussion forum for environmental ethics.

Date:

Fri, 24 May 2002 11:49:36 -0500

Content-Type:

text/plain

Parts/Attachments:

Parts/Attachments

text/plain (172 lines)

Hi Chris,
Thanks for responding, and also for addressing that particular issue,
which is the one I have the most questions about.  Let me see if I
understand the issues.

>Thanks, Jim, for taking the time to post some of this discussion.
>
>You'll be relieved to know that I'm not going to reproduce and comment on
>all of it, just this one point from Lomborg that I think is clearly wrong:
>
>"The $5T is the cost of global warming under BAU. You can only 'do nothing'
>in exactly one way. Therefore there is just one number."
>
>A moment's thought will show that:
>
>If we 'do nothing' about climate change, we do not know exactly how fast
>our economies will grow, we do not know exactly how quickly we will find it
>economic to introduce lower-carbon sources of energy, we do not know
>exactly how much the climate will respond to the extra carbon we put into
>the atmosphere, we do not know exactly how that changed climate will affect
>economic and non-economic activity, and we do not know exactly how the
>valuation of that changed activity will develop.

I had to go back to Lomborg to see exactly where he gets the $5
trillion figure under "business as usual."  In a section titled "Then
what should we do?" (pp. 305-317) he presents the figure as generated
from Nordhaus's and Boyer's (cite below) RICE-99 model.  Lomborg
writes:

        "It is perhaps worth noting that the Kyoto reductions in the
Nordhaus and Boyer model will cause a surprisingly small reduction in
the temperature (0.03 deg. C) in 2100, partly because the developing
countries will increase their CO2 emissions compared to the
business-as-usual model. . . .
        "But what will be the overall cost of these interventions?
Figure 163 [JT: I'll summarize below] shows the cost of the various
types of intervention, with the baseline being a situation with no
global warming.  It shows that the business-as-usual will present
society with a total, one-time cost of $4,820 billion. [footnote
#2610] This cost can also be seen as the cost of the anthropogenic
greenhouse effect as such--if it should prove that our CO2 emissions
have no effect on the climate it would mean a gain of of a little
less than 5 trillion dollars.
        "Of course we would prefer to be without the anthropogenic
greenhouse effect, but the phenomenon is not something we can simply
wish away.  If global warming is coming we must pay the bill--and
then the central question is just how small we can keep this bill.
It turns out, as we have already argued [earlier in the chapter],
that the optimal policy costs a little less.  The total cost in this
case is $4,575 billion, or $245 billion cheaper than taking no
action.  These total savings of $245 billion pertain to a slightly
higher cost in the short term of controlling CO2, offset by the
rather greater advantage of slightly less warming in the long run"
(p. 310).

Figure 163 reads:
Total costs (trillion Y2000$):

Business as usual (no action): $4.820T
Optimal policy: $4.575T
Global stabilization of CO2 at 1990 level: $8.553T
Limit temp. increase to 2.5 deg. C:  $7.803T
Limit temp. increase to 1.5 deg. C: $37.632

Additionally, Lomborg's footnote #2610 reads:
"One should not put too much faith into all these digits, given the
numerous assumptions and approximations--it would be more correct to
say about $5 trillion.  However, the important point is here to
compare the outcome with other scenarios, in which case the relative
costs are much more robust" (p. 426).

Maybe I'm being dense, but I'm still having a bit of trouble seeing
the point to Schneider's criticism here: Lomborg's (actually
Nordhaus's and Boyer's) $5 trillion figure is simply a baseline cost
estimate given present Y2000 conditions of taking no action for
purposes of comparing relative costs of alternative policies.

In my confusion, I've tracked down Nordhaus and Boyer 2000 to see
what it is that they say.  They actually use a round figure of $4
trillion, but I'll assume that Lomborg has legitimate reasons for
coming up with his $4.820 trillion figure (I think Nordhaus may be
using 1990 US dollars).

In a section titled "Costs and Damages," Nordhaus and Boyer write:

        "The focus has been primarily on the abatement costs, but it
is always important to keep in mind that the point of reducing
emissions is to reduce future damages.  Our estimates indicate that
there are likely to be substantial costs of global warming in any of
the cases examined here; the discounted value of damages in the base
case are approximately $4 trillion in present value.
        "The impact of different policies on both costs and damages
is shown in . . . table 8.8.  .  .  .  [These figures] show that the
policies reduce (discounted) damages by only a modest amount--between
$100 and $300 billion out of total damages of $4 trillion.  The
maximum damage reduction from the Kyoto Protocol is $160 billion.
        "Many readers may express surprise about the small impact of
the Kyoto Protocol on the damages from global warming.  The reasons
are that, because there is so much inertia in the climate system and
because the protocol does not limit the emissions of developing
countries, the Kyoto Protocol reduces the global temperature increase
by only a fraction of a degree over the next century.  The other
point .  .  .  is that where- and when-inefficiency raise the costs
of abatement substantially with little or no improvement in benefits.
For example, moving from no controls to the Kyoto Protocol plan with
Annex I [developed countries] trading incurs discounted abatement
cost of $217 billion; however, the discounted value of damages
decreases by only $96 billion.  Moving from the Annex I version to
the no-trade version increases benefits by $65 billion while
increasing costs by $667 billion.  .  .  .
        "The main conclusions that come from an examination of
damages are that there are likely to be substantial damages from
climate change, but that the Kyoto Protocol does virtually nothing to
mitigate the damages" (Nordhaus and Boyer 2000, pp. 163-166).

Jim again: sorry for the length of this, but I guess I'm still a bit
thick on why the $5 trillion base figure is not reputable.  I could
understand if the complaint were that the $5T figure ought to be
proportional to the range of predicted temperature rise (e.g. 1 deg.
C increase=$1T cost; 5 deg. C increase=$5T cost, or whatever), but
that doesn't seem to be Schneider's complaint.

I thought Lomborg's point in using these figures is to demonstrate
relative costs *generally*, as he states in the footnote: "However,
the important point is here to compare the outcome with other
scenarios, in which case the relative costs are much more robust."

I read Lomborg (and Nordhaus) as saying, if we were to do nothing and
policies stay the same, then we could predict up to $5 trillion in
costs associated with global warming.  That figure is to be compared
*generally* with the relative costs of the following alternative
policy scenarios:
Lomborg's Optimal policy: $4.575T
Global stabilization of CO2 at 1990 level: $8.553T
Limit temp. increase to 2.5 deg. C:  $7.803T
Limit temp. increase to 1.5 deg. C: $37.632

Again, I might not be thinking clearly enough here, but it seems to
me that Chris's comment above applies equally to each of the
alternative policy scenarios, i.e.:

>If we 'do nothing' about climate change, we do not know exactly how fast
>our economies will grow, we do not know exactly how quickly we will find it
>economic to introduce lower-carbon sources of energy, we do not know
>exactly how much the climate will respond to the extra carbon we put into
>the atmosphere, we do not know exactly how that changed climate will affect
>economic and non-economic activity, and we do not know exactly how the
>valuation of that changed activity will develop.

Sorry if I'm just being obtuse, but I am grateful at any rate for
your helping me work through these issues and figures.

Jim T.

Nordhaus, William D. and Joseph Boyer.  Warming the World: Economic
Models of Global Warming (Cambridge, MIT Press: 2000).

>
>So any reputable analysis needs to consider the uncertainties, both if we
>'do nothing' and if we 'do something', rather than producing 'just one
>number'. And that is what the reputable analyses do. It seems to me that
>Schneider is right on this fairly central point, and Lomborg, on this
>showing, is wrong.
>
>Chris
>
>
>Chris Hope, Judge Institute of Management,
>University of Cambridge, Cambridge CB2 1AG, UK.
>Voice: +44 1223 338194.   Fax: +44 1223 339701
>e-mail: [log in to unmask]

Top of Message | Previous Page | Permalink

JiscMail Tools


RSS Feeds and Sharing


Advanced Options


Archives

May 2024
April 2024
March 2024
February 2024
January 2024
December 2023
November 2023
October 2023
September 2023
August 2023
July 2023
June 2023
May 2023
April 2023
March 2023
February 2023
January 2023
December 2022
November 2022
October 2022
September 2022
August 2022
July 2022
June 2022
May 2022
April 2022
March 2022
February 2022
January 2022
December 2021
November 2021
October 2021
September 2021
August 2021
July 2021
June 2021
May 2021
April 2021
March 2021
February 2021
January 2021
December 2020
November 2020
October 2020
September 2020
July 2020
June 2020
May 2020
April 2020
March 2020
February 2020
January 2020
December 2019
November 2019
October 2019
May 2019
December 2018
November 2018
October 2018
September 2018
June 2018
May 2018
April 2018
February 2018
January 2018
November 2017
October 2017
September 2017
August 2017
July 2017
June 2017
May 2017
April 2017
February 2017
January 2017
December 2016
September 2016
August 2016
June 2016
May 2016
March 2016
January 2016
December 2015
November 2015
September 2015
August 2015
July 2015
May 2015
April 2015
March 2015
February 2015
January 2015
October 2014
July 2014
June 2014
May 2014
April 2014
March 2014
February 2014
November 2013
October 2013
September 2013
August 2013
July 2013
June 2013
May 2013
March 2013
February 2013
January 2013
November 2012
October 2012
August 2012
July 2012
June 2012
May 2012
April 2012
March 2012
February 2012
January 2012
December 2011
November 2011
October 2011
September 2011
August 2011
July 2011
June 2011
May 2011
April 2011
March 2011
February 2011
January 2011
December 2010
November 2010
March 2010
February 2010
January 2010
December 2009
November 2009
October 2009
July 2009
February 2009
January 2009
December 2008
October 2008
September 2008
July 2008
June 2008
April 2008
March 2008
February 2008
October 2007
August 2007
July 2007
June 2007
May 2007
February 2007
January 2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
2002
2001
2000
1999
1998


JiscMail is a Jisc service.

View our service policies at https://www.jiscmail.ac.uk/policyandsecurity/ and Jisc's privacy policy at https://www.jisc.ac.uk/website/privacy-notice

For help and support help@jisc.ac.uk

Secured by F-Secure Anti-Virus CataList Email List Search Powered by the LISTSERV Email List Manager