JiscMail Logo
Email discussion lists for the UK Education and Research communities

Help for JISC-REPOSITORIES Archives


JISC-REPOSITORIES Archives

JISC-REPOSITORIES Archives


JISC-REPOSITORIES@JISCMAIL.AC.UK


View:

Message:

[

First

|

Previous

|

Next

|

Last

]

By Topic:

[

First

|

Previous

|

Next

|

Last

]

By Author:

[

First

|

Previous

|

Next

|

Last

]

Font:

Proportional Font

LISTSERV Archives

LISTSERV Archives

JISC-REPOSITORIES Home

JISC-REPOSITORIES Home

JISC-REPOSITORIES  December 2009

JISC-REPOSITORIES December 2009

Options

Subscribe or Unsubscribe

Subscribe or Unsubscribe

Log In

Log In

Get Password

Get Password

Subject:

Re: A response from the Wellcome Trust on Conflating OA Repository-Content, Deposit-Locus, and Central-Service: a

From:

Stevan Harnad <[log in to unmask]>

Reply-To:

Stevan Harnad <[log in to unmask]>

Date:

Thu, 10 Dec 2009 15:10:00 -0500

Content-Type:

text/plain

Parts/Attachments:

Parts/Attachments

text/plain (446 lines)

Many thanks to Robert Kiley of the Wellcome Trust (WT) for responding  
to my recommendations on optimising the Trust's Open Access Mandate,  
but unfortunately Robert only repeats points with which I am already  
very familiar, while passing in silence over the actual substantive  
points I have raised, repeatedly, ever since the Wellcome Trust  
mandate was adopted 5 years ago (and even earlier than that).

http://users.ecs.soton.ac.uk/harnad/Hypermail/Amsci/4070.html
http://users.ecs.soton.ac.uk/harnad/Hypermail/Amsci/4498.html
http://openaccess.eprints.org/index.php?/archives/138-guid.html
http://openaccess.eprints.org/index.php?/archives/365-guid.html

Let me summarise the (many) positive aspects of the Wellcome Trust  
Mandate before specifying, once again, the negative aspects that can  
so easily be fixed.

POSITIVE ASPECTS OF THE WELLCOME TRUST (WT) OPEN ACCESS (OA) MANDATE:

(1) The WT OA mandate five years ago (2004) was the world's first  
funder mandate and helped to inspire many others.

(2) The WT OA Mandate not only came earlier than the NIH policy, but  
it was a mandate (requirement) from the very outset, whereas the NIH  
policy lost 2 years by being initially formulated as a request rather  
than a requirement.

(3) The WT in general (and Robert Kiley and Robert Terry in  
particular) have worked valiantly and tirelessly to promote OA and OA  
mandates during the ensuing 5 years.

NEGATIVE ASPECTS:

(1) The WT OA Mandate stipulates direct deposit in PubMedCentral (PMC)  
instead of institutional deposit and central harvesting; this  
counterproductive constraint has since been imitated by other funders  
following WT's example. Institutions are the universal providers of  
all OA output, funded and unfunded, across all disciplines. If funders  
mandate institutional deposit, they encourage and reinforce universal  
adoption of institutional OA mandates (and gain a powerful ally in  
monitoring and ensuring compliance); if funders instead mandate  
central deposit, they discourage and compete with universalizing the  
adoption and implementation of institutional mandates.

(2) The WT OA Mandate permits a delay (embargo) of deposit for up to a  
year after publication. If funders instead mandate immediate  
institutional deposit, with no exceptions, the institutional  
repository's "author email eprint request" Button can provide Almost- 
OA to would-be users while access to the deposit is embargoed;  
otherwise researcher access, usage and impact are needlessly lost  
during the embargo.

(3) The WT OA Mandate allows the option of publishers doing the PMC  
deposits in place of WT's fundees. This not only makes fundee  
compliance vaguer and compliance-monitoring more difficult, but it  
further locks in publisher embargoes (with no possibility of authors  
providing Almost-OA to tide over user needs during the embargo period)  
and further discourages convergent institutional mandates.

All three of these dysfunctional implementational details can be  
easily and fully remedied simply by specifying that deposit should be  
in the fundee's IR (or, if the fundee's does not yet have an IR, in an  
interim IR such as DEPOT) immediately upon acceptance for publication.  
That's all; and the negatives are thereby immediately nullfied and the  
WT funder mandate becomes the optimal model for adoption by other  
funders, as well as a strong impetus to the adoption of complementary  
deposit mandates by institutions.

Now I reply to Robert's responses:

On 9-Dec-09, at 12:20 PM, Robert Kiley (Wellcome Trust)  wrote:

> Stevan
>
> Your last post made a number of comments about PMC, UKPMC and the
> Wellcome Trust, which I'd like to respond to:
>
> 1. Empty repositories?
>
> [1a] You indicate that "PMC (or its emulators)" are bereft of content.
> This is not the case.  PMC currently has around 1.9  million full-text
> articles.  [1b] Looking at the compliance levels for funder mandate,  
> we see
> that around 43% of Trust funded research is made available through
> UKPMC in line with our mandate.  We are actively working to increase
> this figure. [1c]  It is also worth noting that, because of our  
> support for
> gold OA, a significant proportion of these articles are freely
> available at the time of publication.

[1a] Let me define an "empty repository": a repository that captures  
0-15% of its total annual target content.

Why? Because 15% is the default baseline for spontaneous, unmandated  
deposit. You are not doing better than the default baseline if you are  
not capturing significantly more than 15% of your repository's total  
annual target content.

What percentage of the global annual output of peer-reviewed bio- 
medical journal articles -- per year -- do you think that PMC's grand  
total of 1.9 million articles represents?

It's only that (annual) figure (minus 15%) that tells you how non- 
empty a repository is, not the grand total (and certainly not the  
grand total for a central repository whose denominator (the annual  
amount by which you must divide the annual deposits to calculate the  
percentage) consists of all annual biomedical research on the planet  
(or even all annual biomedical research originating from the US).

This is what I called the "denominator fallacy" in my prior posting.

[1b] In contrast, PMC is capturing 43% of WT's target content in 2009.  
That's certainly better than 15% (or NIH's meagre 5% before they  
upgraded their deposit request to a requirement). But that's mandated  
content.

And 5 years after the adoption of the WT mandate, 43% isn't really  
that good either. And it was only last year that WT itself was  
expressing concern about its low compliance rate: http://openaccess.eprints.org/index.php?/archives/365-guid.html

In contrast, institutions that have adopted and implemented deposit  
mandates are doing a good deal better than that: Over 60% and well on  
the road to 100% about 2 years after adoption. http://fcms.its.utas.edu.au/scieng/comp/project.asp?lProjectId=1830

And the reason for the successful institutional mandates' success is  
quite evident: Institutions are the quotidial employers of their  
researchers, not just their occasional funders. And they have annual  
performance reviews for salary, promotion and tenure. Institutions are  
in a position to mandate -- as the University of Liege has notably  
done -- that the mechanism for submitting one's annual publications  
for performance review is henceforth to deposit them in their IR;  
otherwise the publications will be invisible. This is a simple  
internal bureaucratic requirement, rather like the ubiquitous  
transition from submitting on paper to submitting online.

Institutions, as we all know, are also very eager that their  
researchers should receive research funding. Hence institutions are  
eager to be involved in helping researchers prepare grant applications  
as well as to ensure that they fulfill all grant requirements if  
funded. Fundees' institutions are hence funders' natural allies in  
ensuring and monitoring compliance with the funder's deposit mandate  
-- as long as the designated deposit locus is institutional. Moreover,  
funders mandating institutional deposit of the articles resulting from  
the research they fund, and institutions' involvement in ensuring  
compliance, also encourages institutions to go on and mandate deposit  
of the rest of their research output too.

But if it is instead stipulated by the funder -- and I have to repeat  
this each time: for no good reason at all, since it confers no  
advantages whatsoever, either functional or practical, over  
institutional deposit, only disadvantages -- that deposit must be  
central, then the fundee's institution is in no better position than  
the funder to ensure and monitor compliance. In addition, the  
institution then has the opposition of its researchers to contend  
with, if ever the institution contemplates adopting a deposit mandate  
of its own: Researchers (quite understandable, and justifiably) do not  
want to have to deposit willy-nilly in divergent multiple loci,  
institution-internal as well as institution-external. Add to that the  
further confusion added by the fact that fundee "compliance" can be  
fulfilled by *publishers* depositing in PMC instead of fundees, and  
after a one-year embargo, and you have both grant fulfillment  
conditions and mandate incentive conditions as ill-served and hard to  
monitor as they could possible be.

And, again, for no good positive reason whatsoever.

[1c] Yes, the WT money that could have been spent on supporting more  
research, when it is instead redirected to paying for Gold OA  
publication, does increase the uptake of Gold OA somewhat. But is that  
the objective? Or is the objective rather to increase OA as much as  
possible -- which is what the Green OA deposit mandate itself would  
do, if compliance were indeed insured and monitored.

As to the best way to contend with the 1-year embargo at this point --  
that's up to WT to decide. 63% of journals already endorse making  
institutional deposits OA immediately upon publication. If WT finds it  
a better use of its research money to pay for immediate Gold OA for  
the remaining 37% (rather than relying on the Institutional  
Repositories' "email eprint request" Button to allow the author to  
provide almost-immediate, "Almost OA" during the embargo), that's a  
judgment call. But it's not an argument for insisting on central  
deposit rather than institutional.

Note, though, that WT is on the side of the angels in having mandated  
OA already, rather than just offering to subsidize Gold OA. The  
trouble is that the "mandated Green OA deposit plus subsidized Gold OA  
option" policy is far less generalizable, for example, for poorer  
funders, or funders more anxious to use their scarce funds to fund  
more research rather than to subsidize Gold OA publishing. This is  
especially today, when OA can be had without cost, by mandating Green  
OA and just letting subscriptions continue to pay for publishing. And  
this remains true until/unless Green OA ever makes subscriptions no  
longer sustainable. Then (and only then) a transition to Gold OA will  
be payable out of institutions' windfall subscription cancellation  
savings -- and for a lot less than today's Gold OA's pre-emptive sking  
price, since the only thing left to pay for then will be peer review  
-- without the need to syphon away any additional research money.

Moreover, the example of pre-emptive payment for Gold OA has inspired  
another nonstarter, from funders and institutions that are not yet on  
the side of the angels: They are redirecting scarce research or  
institutional funds today, needlessly, to pay for Gold OA today  
without even mandating OA, as WT has done. That's the worst of all  
possible worlds (and encouraged by the example of needless and  
ineffectual profligacy on the part of others, even when they do couple  
it with a Green OA mandate too...)


> 2. "National PMC's are a joke"
>
> The idea that UKPMC is a "joke" is not shared by the Wellcome Trust,
> or indeed the other 7 biomedical research funders in the UK who have
> established (and funded) this repository.
>
> You suggest that UKPMC simply holds UK content.  This is not the case.
> It holds **all** the PMC content, but each "locality" (UK, Canada
> etc) can build services in top of that to ensure that it meets the
> needs of the research community we are trying to serve.

That's all splendid, and not the joke at all.

The joke is the notion that all these countries need a national PMC as  
the place to mandate deposit!

Of course all manner of harvesting services can be superadded to any  
number of harvested collections -- national, disciplinary or what have  
you. That's not the joke. The joke is that national funders are  
slavishly adopting the wrong-headed notion that they, like NIH/PMC,  
need their own national, central place to deposit their mandated  
contents -- instead of doing what NIH/PMC should have done in the  
first place (and should convert as soon as possible to doing now),  
which is to mandate institutional deposit, and harvest/import from  
there to any central collections or services they may wish to provide.

> In January 2010 we will be launching a new UKPMC site which will  
> offer users:
>
> A) A single access point to around 20 million bibliographic records -
> drawn from PubMed, Biological Patents, Agricola and Clinical
> Guidelines databases - as well as the 1.5m+ full text articles in
> UKPMC

Splendid. But now please explain to me why the worthy and welcome goal  
of offering *users* a single access point for all these worthwhile  
contents needs to be reached by requiring UK-funded *authors* to  
deposit in UKPMC to fulfill their deposit mandates, rather than in  
their own IRs?

(And I do hope you won't reply that it's in order to accommodate the  
publishers, who need to deposit in UKPMC! Those articles are by UK  
fundees too! Let those fundees simply, and uniformly, deposit all  
their (mandated) articles in their own IRs, regardless of whether they  
are published in paid Gold OA journals, free Gold OA journals,  
subscription journals with OA embargoes, or subscription journals  
without OA embargoes: One size fits all, funders and institutions  
alike, across nations as well as disciplines, for both funded and  
unfunded research: Deposit institutionally.

> B) Additional, local content.  This includes guidelines from NICE and
> other NHS bodies, plus relevant (i.e. biomedical) theses derived from
> EthOS.  So, by way of example, when you search the new site for say
> "management of stroke" you will be presented with relevant PubMed
> citations, full-text articles, UK clinical guidelines etc in one
> search.

All very valuable stuff -- but nothing in this is contingent on  
mandating central deposit. Harvesting of distributed content is the  
name of the game, in the online era. (We don't deposit directly in  
google either. Google harvests distributed locally deposited content.)

> C) New citation services.  For every article (be it full text or just
> the bibliographic citation) you will be able to see all the papers
> which that paper cited, as well as all the other articles which cite
> that paper.

Lovely, stuff but nothing to do with the only point at issue here,  
which is whether or not mandating funders have any good reason to  
require divergent central deposit instead of convergent institutional  
deposit. (The latter might even help accelerate the institutional  
mandates you'll need to turn those bibliographic citations into full- 
texts -- at least for living authors...)

> D) New text-mining services.  Our colleagues at EBI and NaCTeM have
> build tools to textmine the content in UKPMC.  In the first release
> (January 2010) users will be able to see in a "summary box" which will
> provide details of what genes/proteins, organisms etc are discussed in
> the paper they are viewing.  Over the next 18 months this textmining
> functionality will be developed further in include chemical compounds,
> disease names etc etc.

Again very valuable, and again completely orthogonal to the question  
of locus of deposit -- which, to repeat, is the only one I keep  
banging on about.

(If funders wish to mandate deposit in specific formats, such as XML,  
they can do that equally well regardless of locus of deposit -- though  
I would not myself recommend over-constraining format requirements at  
this early stage, when it is the articles that are missing and sorely  
needed, rather than the documents already being accessible, and only  
the right format being sorely needed. And if, in contrast, the deposit  
tagging and format are being enriched by some other central service,  
rather than the author, that too can be done irrespective of locus of  
deposit, again through central importation or harvesting.)

> The "franchise" model that PMC uses is akin to that developed for the
> human genome project inasmuch as content is mirrored to a number of
> sites (e.g. NCBI, Sanger, and DDBJ) but each centre develops their own
> interface to this content.  So, the core content at PMC, UKPMC and PMC
> Canada is identical -- but each centre will develop their own
> valued-added services.

The "franchise" model is equally compatible with central deposit and  
with distributed institutional deposit and central harvesting...

> The UKPMC Funders Group - led by the Wellcome Trust - are, with the
> support of European partners, exploring the possibility of creating a
> single, Europe-wide OA repository for peer reviewed biomedical
> research papers -- a Europe PMC.  A workshop to discuss this is taking
> place on the 2nd December at the Berlin 7 meeting.  [See:
> http://www.berlin7.org/spip.php?article74]

All these collections and re-collections of biomedical research papers  
and services are welcome, but have nothing to do with mandated deposit  
locus.

> 3. Why the Trust favours the author-pays model
> ***
> The Wellcome Trust has always argued that:
>
> A) dissemination costs are simply research costs
> B) publishers add-value to the research article

Fine. Call the costs what one may: those publication costs and values  
are being paid for in full by subscriptions today. What is missing is  
access to those publications (for those whose institutions can't  
afford the subscription costs). Green OA provides that access, in  
full. And mandates provide Green OA, with no extra cost. It's up to WT  
if they want to spend more research money on reforming publishing,  
rather than just providing the access that is missing. But let that  
not be mistaken or misrepresented as the fastest, cheapest or surest  
way to provide the missing access. It is simply using research money  
to try to reform publishing.

Nor can WT represent favouring the payment for Gold OA with scarce  
research funds over providing Green OA at no extra cost as something  
that favours OA: It does not. It simply diverts research money to pay  
pre-emptively for Gold OA, when it is not even needed; it disfavours  
the cost-free Green way of providing OA; and it sets an unfortunate  
example for other funders contemplating what they can do to increase OA.

> It follows, therefore, that these costs have to be met -- and that is
> what the Wellcome Trust (and others) do.

It only follows that those costs have to be met if there is also a  
reason why research money has to be spent on reforming publishing  
today, when what is really needed today, urgently, is more research  
access, not less research money, nor publishing reform.

(Publishing reform will be needed, and will happen, if and only if and  
when universal Green OA makes subscription journal publishing  
unsustainable. But if and when universal Green OA ever does so, it  
will, by the very same token, also release the subscription  
cancellation funds to pay for Gold OA without the need to redirect  
scarce research funds. Indeed, universal Green-OA-driven subscription  
collapse will also force journal publishing to cut obsolete products  
and services (such as the paper edition, the online edition, access- 
provision and archiving) and their associated costs, downsizing to  
just the service of peer review. The distributed network of  
institutional repositories (and any harvester services thereover) will  
do the access-provision and archiving. So instead of receiving less  
research funding, researchers' institutions will enjoy a surplus from  
their annual windfall subscription cancellation savings.

> It is also worth pointing out that when an APC fee is met, the Trust
> requires the publisher to provide a number of services:
>
> A) Deposit the final version - marked up to an XML standard - directly
> into PMC, where it must be made freely available at the time of
> publication.  [So, no embargo, no "email request buttons", and no work
> on behalf of the author.]

If you offered your fundees the choice (without fear or favour) of  
spending the WT research money on research or spending it to spare  
themselves the few keystrokes it takes to deposit their postprints  
(63%) and fulfill email eprint requests (37%), do you have any doubt  
as to what choice they would make? Especially if the designated locus  
of deposit were institutional, and hence they were already depositing  
their unfunded research that way...

> B) Attach a licence to these articles, thus ensuring that anyone who
> want to re-use the work (e.g. text-mining, creating translations,
> re-using for different audiences etc) can do so.  Whether such rights
> extend to author manuscripts is, at best, unclear.

More important, those rights and re-uses are completely superfluous.  
What's urgently needed (and prominently missing) today is online  
access to the articles, free for all. What comes with that territory  
is the capability of any user to search, link, read online, download,  
print-off, and data-crunch a personal copy. In addition, harvesters  
like google can and will harvest and invert it. "Different audiences"  
can use the same URL. Translations (for the lucky few where it's  
wanted) can, as always, be handled on a case by case basis.

Let's talk again about any "text-mining" beyond this when there's  
enough OA text to make it worth talking about.

> C) These articles can also be included in the OA subset, thus allowing
> institutions (and others) to harvest, via OAI, relevant full-text
> content.

That sentiment is not unworthy of Marie Antoinette! "Let the  
institutions harvest back their very own content, because we have  
elected to mandate that it must be deposit institution- 
externally." (Harvesting, for the record, is something central  
harvesters do over distributed providers of the content, not the  
reverse, i.e., not distributed providers of the content, harvesting it  
back from an institution-external central deposit locus where their  
own content providers have been required to deposit it, instead of  
depositing it institution-internally in the first -- and only --  
place. (That's like saying, let everyone deposit their content in  
google, and then harvest it back if they want it locally.)

SUMMARY: Not one substantive reason has been given for WT's continuing  
insistence on central deposit rather than institutional deposit (and  
central harvesting). Nor has a compelling reason been given for  
favouring paid Gold OA over free Green OA (but if WT mandated  
institutional deposit, this would become a minor matter, because as  
more institutions added their institutional mandates to WT's and other  
funders' mandates, the absurdity -- and non-scaleability -- of paying  
pre-emptively for Gold OA today, rather than just depositing for Green  
OA at this time -- while the potential funds to pay for Gold OA are  
still locked into subscriptions that are paying for subscription  
publication in full --  would become more and more obvious. The  
confusion and uncertainty about this today are simply a result of the  
extreme sparseness of OA content -- whether Green or Gold -- today [c.  
15%], as well as the extreme rarity of OA mandates [c. 100/10,000].)

Best regards,

Stevan Harnad

>
> Best regards
> Robert Kiley
>
> Wellcome Trust

Top of Message | Previous Page | Permalink

JiscMail Tools


RSS Feeds and Sharing


Advanced Options


Archives

May 2024
April 2024
March 2024
February 2024
January 2024
December 2023
November 2023
October 2023
September 2023
August 2023
July 2023
June 2023
May 2023
April 2023
March 2023
February 2023
January 2023
December 2022
November 2022
October 2022
September 2022
August 2022
July 2022
June 2022
May 2022
April 2022
March 2022
February 2022
January 2022
December 2021
November 2021
October 2021
September 2021
August 2021
July 2021
June 2021
May 2021
April 2021
March 2021
February 2021
January 2021
December 2020
November 2020
October 2020
September 2020
August 2020
July 2020
June 2020
May 2020
April 2020
March 2020
February 2020
January 2020
December 2019
November 2019
October 2019
September 2019
August 2019
July 2019
June 2019
May 2019
April 2019
March 2019
February 2019
January 2019
December 2018
November 2018
October 2018
September 2018
August 2018
July 2018
June 2018
May 2018
April 2018
March 2018
February 2018
January 2018
December 2017
November 2017
October 2017
September 2017
August 2017
July 2017
June 2017
May 2017
April 2017
March 2017
February 2017
January 2017
December 2016
November 2016
October 2016
September 2016
August 2016
July 2016
June 2016
May 2016
April 2016
March 2016
February 2016
January 2016
December 2015
November 2015
October 2015
September 2015
August 2015
July 2015
June 2015
May 2015
April 2015
March 2015
February 2015
January 2015
December 2014
November 2014
October 2014
September 2014
August 2014
July 2014
June 2014
May 2014
April 2014
March 2014
February 2014
January 2014
December 2013
November 2013
October 2013
September 2013
August 2013
July 2013
June 2013
May 2013
April 2013
March 2013
February 2013
January 2013
December 2012
November 2012
October 2012
September 2012
August 2012
July 2012
June 2012
May 2012
April 2012
March 2012
February 2012
January 2012
December 2011
November 2011
October 2011
September 2011
August 2011
July 2011
June 2011
May 2011
April 2011
March 2011
February 2011
January 2011
December 2010
November 2010
October 2010
September 2010
August 2010
July 2010
June 2010
May 2010
April 2010
March 2010
February 2010
January 2010
December 2009
November 2009
October 2009
September 2009
August 2009
July 2009
June 2009
May 2009
April 2009
March 2009
February 2009
January 2009
December 2008
November 2008
October 2008
September 2008
August 2008
July 2008
June 2008
May 2008
April 2008
March 2008
February 2008
January 2008
December 2007
November 2007
October 2007
September 2007
August 2007
July 2007
June 2007
May 2007
April 2007
March 2007
February 2007
January 2007
December 2006
November 2006
October 2006
September 2006
August 2006
July 2006
June 2006
May 2006
April 2006
March 2006
February 2006
January 2006
November 2005
October 2005


JiscMail is a Jisc service.

View our service policies at https://www.jiscmail.ac.uk/policyandsecurity/ and Jisc's privacy policy at https://www.jisc.ac.uk/website/privacy-notice

For help and support help@jisc.ac.uk

Secured by F-Secure Anti-Virus CataList Email List Search Powered by the LISTSERV Email List Manager