JiscMail Logo
Email discussion lists for the UK Education and Research communities

Help for ITALIAN-STUDIES Archives


ITALIAN-STUDIES Archives

ITALIAN-STUDIES Archives


ITALIAN-STUDIES@JISCMAIL.AC.UK


View:

Message:

[

First

|

Previous

|

Next

|

Last

]

By Topic:

[

First

|

Previous

|

Next

|

Last

]

By Author:

[

First

|

Previous

|

Next

|

Last

]

Font:

Proportional Font

LISTSERV Archives

LISTSERV Archives

ITALIAN-STUDIES Home

ITALIAN-STUDIES Home

ITALIAN-STUDIES  September 2002

ITALIAN-STUDIES September 2002

Options

Subscribe or Unsubscribe

Subscribe or Unsubscribe

Log In

Log In

Get Password

Get Password

Subject:

the challenge and reward of studying Sicily

From:

Filippo Sabetti <[log in to unmask]>

Reply-To:

Scholarly discussions in any field of Italian studies <[log in to unmask]>

Date:

Fri, 20 Sep 2002 13:59:05 -0400

Content-Type:

text/plain

Parts/Attachments:

Parts/Attachments

text/plain (409 lines)

italian-studies: Scholarly discussions in any field of Italian studies

fyi


THE MAFIA AND ALL THAT:
THINKING THEORETICALLY AND COMPARATIVELY ABOUT
SICILIAN HISTORY

Filippo Sabetti
Department of Political Science
McGill University
Montreal, Quebec Canada

[Nota bene: a slightly different version is scheduled to come out in the
November issue of ITALIAN POLITICS & SOCIETY, the Review of the
Conference Group on Italian Politics & Society (CONGRIPS). For more
information about the review and about membership in CONGRIPS (everyone
is welcome!), List members are urged to contact its secretary Richard
Katz at Johns Hopkins University [log in to unmask], or its president
Filippo Sabetti, <[log in to unmask]]

James Fentress, Rebels and Mafiosi: Death in a Sicilian Landscape.
Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2000, pp. 297.
Lucy Riall, Sicily and the Unification of Italy: Liberal Policy and
Local Power, 1859-1866. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1998, pp. 252.

The history of Sicily is no by means unique, but it constitutes a rich
laboratory for thinking theoretically and comparatively about politics
and a general puzzle in the social sciences: how individuals relate to
one another so as to realize their productive potentials in an
interdependent situation which characterizes public affairs. This is,
after all, why some of us became interested in Sicilian development. If
we cannot, for a variety of reasons, do our own archival research, we
can turn to the work of historians who provide us with a data base as
far back as the ancient world. To be sure, most historians do not use
the theoretical distinctions or language of social science but in their
own fashion they address critical issues in several topics dear to
comparativists: the architecture of choice (Jones 2001),  and
constitutional political economy more generally (Buchanan and Tullock
1962; V. Ostrom [1982] 1999); collective-action dilemmas in
self-governance (E. Ostrom 1990); the challenge of understanding
passages to modernity “as seeing like a state” (Scott 1998); law and the
political basis of economic development (Berman 1983); dynamics of
contentious politics (McAdam, Tarrow, Tilly 2001); positive and dark
sides of social  capital (Coleman 1990; Levi 1996; and Putnam 1993);
conditions under which citizens give, refuse, and withdraw their consent
to government (Levi 1997); what makes government (in)effective (Tendler
1997), and what leads people to work outside the law (De Soto 1989);
and, of course, the political economy of crimes and punishments
(Gambetta 1993; Varese 2001). In short, problematics and issues in
Sicilian history lie, in the words of Mark Lichbach and Alan Zuckerman,
within the “ambitious scope of inquiry” of comparative politics. For,
“no political phenomenon is foreign to it; no level of analysis is
irrelevant, and no time period beyond its reach” (Lichbach and Zuckerman
1997, 4).

The works of James Fentress and Lucy Riall are cases in point. The
historical knowledge they each advance can be viewed in a complementary
fashion. Both offer much data to social scientists eager to uncover what
architecture of choice and logic of institutional change, if any, may be
at work in contentious political experiments and to understand success
and failure in the political economy of decisions and institutions. The
architecture of choice and institutional changes discussed in the two
works are, in turn, embedded in preceding rounds, and a central issue
remains: how far back do we need to go in order to trace the origins of
19th century issues and problems?  A satisfactory answer depends on all
sorts of factors, some of them strictly disciplinary in nature. But a
brief look at what we now know about earlier changes (or lack of them)
helps to understand the historical context of what preoccupies Riall and
Fentress and why Sicilian history remains a laboratory for rewarding
social science explorations.

Economic historians like Stephan Epstein (1992) have shown what many
social scientists are still reluctant to acknowledge: that feudalism and
capitalism (and markets) coexisted with varying degrees of success in
Sicilian development before the eighteenth century. Despite the use of
seemingly ‘archaic’ tools (oxen and scratch ploughs), both yield ratios
and production for hectare in Sicily up to the eighteenth century were
equivalent to, or higher than, those in most advanced northern European
countries (England, Flanders, the Netherlands), and substantially better
than in northern Italy or the Baltic regions. In other words, the North
European model of agricultural work is not in itself an indicator of
progress: had it actually been adopted in Sicily, it would have caused
an economic disaster. This conclusion leads Epstein to warn us not to
project failings in Sicilian agriculture during the eighteenth-century
onto previous centuries.

From the eighteenth century, we can derive other lessons. By the 1770s,
a concern for the failings of the Sicilian political economy and the
consequences that these were having on Sicilian life was widespread
among members of the Sicilian baronial and intellectual classes (often
the same persons). So when the new Neapolitan viceroy, Domenico
Caracciolo, fresh from his long sojourn in France, went to Sicily in
1781, he could not have found a more favorable climate for reforms. Yet
it was not before long that he alienated even the very same people he
thought needed to be delivered from bondage.  How was that possible,
given the widespread support for institutional changes? The answer is
familiar to those who study what Tocqueville in his book on the ancien
regime in France called “the literary view of politics.”

As soon as Caracciolo reached Sicily, he confounded in indiscriminate
hatred all things Sicilian – both the worst and what was best in
Sicilian political tradition. As a result, he missed the opportunities
for reform, transforming baronial opposition to some reforms into a
defense of the Sicilian nation. The barons, having acquired a new
awareness of their constitutional rights, proceeded in 1812 to press
ahead with their own reform: the abolition of feudalism sweeping away
baronial jurisdiction and feudal dues and privileges, and the creation
of a new parliamentary monarchy – the so-called Anglo-Sicilian
constitution. The problem was that the range of factors that impinged on
the ability of Sicilian leaders to govern was far greater than that
experienced by their British counterparts. By 1814, the constitutional
barons could neither make use of parliament nor manage public affairs
without it. What they needed was a long time span in order to work out
or solve the accumulation of governmental issues and problems generated
by the constitutional reform experiment; but time they did not have as a
result of the Congress of Vienna. Still, the chief problem for Sicily
was not the “Anglo-Sicilian” constitution of 1812 but rather its
suppression and the extension of absolutist rule in 1816 – the starting
point in both Fentress and Riall.

From the vantage point of preceding Sicilian history and from a concern
for self-governance, the creation of a legal-rational order à la Weber
in 1816 represents a breakdown and not the beginning of modernization in
Sicily.This is so, not because the legal-rational order à la Weber was
imposed from the outside (a fuorviante or misleading issue), but because
rather than facilitating individual and collective efforts on behalf of
common interests shared by islanders, centralized government and
administration created an antithesis of interests between rulers and
ruled, and between landowners and landless. The antithesis evolved into
successive revolts, culminating in the very collapse of the Kingdom of
Two Sicilies and the creation of the Kingdom of Italy in 1860-61. But
the iron law of oligarchy inherent in the forced creation of unity
through centralized government and administration remained, just as the
proprietary claims of great landowners continued to be determinants of
the human condition in most of the countryside.

The creators of Italian unification deliberately did not set out to
victimize people.  Fentress and Riall found Italian leaders assumed or
took for granted that the reconstitution of agricultural and communal
activities as a function of their state making  - what in other contexts
James C. Scott (1998) has more recently characterized as “seeing and
thinking like a State” - would have primarily beneficial effects. Why,
then, the gap between expectations and results?

The two authors find it useful to go back to the problem of
governability under the post-1816 Bourbons. They both emphasize the
challenges that centralized government and administration faced before
and after 1860 with respect to public order and local-central government
relations. Their narrative can be taken to suggest, correctly, that many
of the difficulties in government performance can be attributed to
institutional problems, including the issues how to create an
administrative class in a short-time span and, at the same time, secure
coordination and compliance through bureaucratic means from an unwilling
population. Riall is a careful historian, and she write insightfully. We
must be grateful that she has given so much of her skills and time to
the study of Sicily. On three points, however, I find Fentress’s
analysis more persuasive.

First, I find untenable Riall’s belief that a unification à la Gramsci
could have  taken place if Cavour had somehow stopped being Cavour and
instead acted like a French Revolutionist; such if/then propositions
ignore the actual people and facts. Here is where historians can learn
from social scientists concerned with how it is possible for (liberal)
governments to secure compliance for their decisions without the consent
of the governed/ruled. Second, what might more realistically have
occurred and, if it had, would have given Cavour and his government
greater support, legitimacy, and consensus would be their having acted
on the political decentralization experiment suggested, among others by
Ferrara in his now famous 1860 memorandum to Cavour (not mentioned by
either Fentress or Riall), and, at the same time, ceased the
confiscation of church property in Sicily, where a majority of people
were strongly attached to the church (discussed by Fentress). These
possibilities are based on what we know about the people and facts, but
the rush of events militated against them. Third, if Riall had looked
more closely at the identification and aspirations of Sicilian democrats
from the 1840s to the revolt of 1866, she would have found what Fentress
presents: that most Sicilian democrats were not Jacobins, or “Gramscian”
ante litteram.  Most, if not all, were political and not social
democrats. They wanted self-government, with independence or autonomy
for Sicily based on a revised version of the 1812 constitution.  Many of
them also wanted to resurrect the symbols of the Sicilian nation,
including its flag, coat of arms and parliament, suppressed in 1816.
(The issue of the Sicilian language, a written language since the twelth
century, with its own dictionary since the sixteenth is more
complicated. Suffice it to say that Sicilian-Italian dictionaries
continued to be published after 1866 and to this very day. In March
2002, the Feltrinelli, Dante and Flaccovio bookstores in dowtown Palermo
each offered one book-shelf of reprinted and new dictionaries. The last
volume of a projected five-volume comprehensive dictionary started in
the 1970s is scheduled to appear by 2004.)  Most Sicilian democrats
anticipated that a free labor market together with communal government
and parliament recast on the principles of self-government would
seriously diminish the ability of large landowners to determine living
conditions for those in the countryside. But, the very reiteration of
centralized government and administration in 1860 prevented that to
happen. There is much force in Raymond Grew’s well known conclusion that
the rush of unexpected success spoiled the Risorgimento.

Thus, most Sicilian peasants – and especially those living in the
interior where large estates predominated - found themselves locked in a
many-person analogue to the prisoner’s dilemma of modern game theory.
Sidney Sonnino (1876) referred to this as “the iron circle.” On the one
hand, labor contracts were imposed on workers by a monopoly of large
landowners or their agents and supported by the arms of the state; on
the other, the same villagers bore the cost of government, without
having any voice in its decisions and while deriving little benefit from
its actions. Most Sicilians were thus left without legal remedies while
the central government would not tolerate any kind of illegal remedy. A
logic of mutually destructive relationships came to dominate work and
community life. How did people cope with, or extricate themselves from,
this situation?

Sicilians sought in several ways to restructure a game of life rigged
against them. Riall ends her narrative with the revolt against the
central government in 1866. Fentress suggests why Sicily and Piedmont
cannot be quite compared in the way that Riall does, for they “were two
mismatched pieces of a political puzzle. When Piedmont tried to force
Sicily into a political and institutional straightjacket, the
influential and authoritative citizens of Palermo, seeing that their
power and local autonomy was under threat, renewed their alliance with
segments of the revolutionary and counterrevolutionary parties, as well
as with the dangerous classes that both sides of the combat had tried to
recruit.” (p. 254).

Fentress continues the narrative beyond 1866. His archival research on
the Sicilian interior and coastal towns uncovers new and fresh evidence
about the origins of the mafia. The story of what happened is far more
interesting, more unexpected, than any sociological and anthropological
theorizing of the 1960s and 1970s led us to believe.
Fentress argues – convincingly, in my view - that the story of the mafia
must be understood against the background of the uprisings of 1820,
1848, 1860 and 1866 and, more generally, Sicily’s struggle for freedom
in the first half of the nineteenth century. In fact, many of the social
and political modes of behavior that have evolved, and often become ways
of life, in Sicily must be understood as responses to strictly political
phenomena. Fentress places in sharp relief the political basis of
agrarian problems and the different types of property rights and
economies that could be found in coastal plains and in the interior. His
study stresses the importance of these differences – climatic,
geographic, agricultural, and institutional, including property rights –
for a proper understanding of the emergence of the mafia. Variations in
the historical and institutional context matter. Just as I found that
the mafia of Villalba, in the Sicilian interior, developed out of a
civic, self-help tradition (Sabetti 2002), Fentress has found that the
mafia of Misilmeri and other coastal towns without large estates
developed out of a revolutionary tradition. Our respective studies are
complementary not contradictory. Fentress’s finding will also challenge
those who have come to attach a particular leftist (=positive) meaning
to revolution and brotherhood.

A chief value of Fentress’s work is that it transforms into a variable
what is often viewed as a constant: the emergence of mafia groups as
illicit, criminal enterprises. Like my own work, Fentress does not
challenge the empirical validity of the received wisdom (espoused by
Riall) where it is relevant but rather its generalizability to the
entire Western Sicily across time and space since the 1860s. After all,
how much do we really know about the history of the more than three
hundred villages and towns of Western Sicily? That the mafia was – as
Riall suggests - some kind of privatized Leviathan is doubtful, unless
of course she is not using the term Leviathan as Hobbes intended.

Conclusions about the origins of the mafia and how mafia groups worked
in practice are far from settled, for several complicating reasons.
First, given our empiricist epistemology, many social scientists have
increasingly adopted a positivist, unproblematic view of the monopoly of
state powers and seldom raised the problem, noted by Michael Taylor
(1982), of when states have possessed an actual monopoly on the use of
force. We have thus neglected to appreciate what Sonnino emphasized and
other studies beyond Sicily have found (such as De Soto, Ostrom and
Scott) - that is, we have tended to ignore the fact that people, in some
basic sense, build their own social and political realities and
opportunities and that what officialdom in the formal regime may do is
only part of the story. If some concepts or institutions do not work, or
work against them, people will make their own adaptations, which may
become extreme forms of illegal problem-solving when officialdom
continues to think it can govern but people are actually going their own
way.

Second, Fentress is quite good in reminding us that the crimes that
mafia groups are usually associated with are older than the mafia
itself; it is not always easy to distinguish which crimes are the
mafia’s and which are not. In addition, those who wish to argue that
mafia brotherhoods did evil deeds just for the sake of doing evil or
violence are on shaky grounds (p.219). Like other analysts (Gambetta;
Sabetti; Varese), Fentress has found that violence is a means, not an
end. An outlaw regime can gain legitimacy through the protection
services it offers and then exploit the position it has acquired,
recreating the problems of political organization that plague the lawful
regime. Consider the Mugnai della Posa in the Palermo area (due-paying
millers). By 1874, they had managed to transform themselves into a
protection racket as a way to enforce their fixed prices and excluding
outsiders (p.165). Does this happen only in Sicily?  No need to call up
evidence from biblical times. Recall the work of the Family Compact of
Upper and Lower Canada in the 1830s. Federterra used similar practices
in Tuscany and other parts of North Italy to control the supply of labor
and employment during the Biennio Rosso. Fentress makes us appreciate
why many unions in the United States have been bastions of organized
crime, and why some Sicilian antimafia groups after 1918 and 1945 had
difficulties in not becoming mirror images of what they sought to
destroy.

Third, mafia groups as outlaw regimes enjoyed the support of many, if
not most, common people who stood to profit from them and who did not
regard state laws as the final determinant of what was criminal or
illegal. Short of exiting Sicily, other alternatives available to local
people were, if not worse than what was done by the mafia, not always
desirable. Fentress lends empirical support to Margaret Levi’s analysis
of under what conditions citizens give, refuse and withdraw their
consent to government, legal and illegal.

Fourth, the conventional wisdom has fostered much misunderstanding about
why Sicily’s own ruling group seems to have made no attempt to curb the
growth of the mafia. Fentress draws attention to two new, and more
plausible, explanations. The first is that  Sicily’s ruling group stood
in ambiguous relation to the state; the revolutionaries and followers of
Mazzini, shut out after 1866, allied themselves with the extralegal
structure of power, making different mafia groups clients of the
revolutionary party. The other reason why Sicily’s ruling group made no
real attempt to confront local mafia groups is that by the 1890s the old
ruling, revolutionary, group had its back to the wall (pp. 250-52). If
Fentress is correct, we need to recast much of our knowledge of the
workers’s leagues of the 1890s and the very history of Corleone.

Fifth, the polemical use of the term mafia in public discourse and the
dynamics of contention have often clouded points one, two, three and
four. The mafia as piovra has a long and rueful history in polemical
writings about Sicilian criminality. The world of Sicilian criminals and
that of the myths and half-truths that surround their activities
overlap, making the task of distinguishing fact from fantasy exceedingly
difficult. Against this backdrop, the Caso Notarbartolo as recounted by
Fentress becomes persuasive. Still, it is not clear how Fentress could
have incorrectly identified Giovanni Giolitti, the prime minister of
Liberal Italy, as Antonio Giolitti.

The work of Lucy Riall reminds us that there is more to Sicily’s
political experience than violence and corruption. The work of James
Fentress answers the question that Giovanni Falcone (1991), the Sicilian
antimafia magistrate, raised before he was killed in 1992: “Why is it
that men, some even endowed with real intellectual abilities, are
compelled to devise for themselves a criminal career in order to survive
with dignity?”  Falcone’s concern is not that far off from the central
puzzle in the social sciences mentioned at the outset. Both works excel
in showing that it is possible to do historical research about the mafia
in terms that transcend the particularities of Sicily, allowing us to
think theoretically and comparatively about collective-action dilemmas
across time and space.

References Cited

Berman, Harold 1983. Law and Revolution: The Formation of the Western
Legal Tradition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press
Buchanan, James M. and Gordon Tullock 1962. The Calculus of Consent. Ann
Arbor: The University of Michigan Press
Coleman, James S. 1990. The Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge:
Harvard University Press
De Soto, Hernando 1989. The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the
Third World. New York: Harper & Row
Epstein, Stephan R. 1992. An Island for Itself: Economic Development and
Social Change in Late Medieval Sicily. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press
Falcone, Giovanni 1991. Cose di Cosa Nostra, in collaborazione con
Marcelle Padovani. Milan: Rizzoli
Gambetta, Diego 1993. The Sicilian Mafia. Cambridge: Harvard University
Press
Jones, Bryan D. 2001. Politics and the Architecture of Choice: Bounded
Rationality and Governance. Chicago: University of Chicago Press
Levi, Margaret 1996. “Social and Unsocial Capital.” Politics & Society
24 (March):45-55
-------- 1997. Consent, Dissent and Patriotism. New York: Cambridge
University Press
Lichback, Mark I. and Alan S. Zuckerman eds. 1997. Comparative Politics:
Rationality, Cutlure and Structure. New York: Cambridge University Press

McAdam, Doug, Sidney Tarrow, Charles Tilly 2001. Dynamics of Contention.
New York: Cambridge University Press
Ostrom, Elinor 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of
Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press

Ostrom, Vincent [1982] 1999.  “A Forgotten Tradition: The Constitutional
Level of Analysis. Pp.151-165. In Polycentric Governance and Development
ed. Michael D. McGinnis. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press
Sabetti, Filippo 2002. Village Politics and the Mafia in Sicily.
Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press
Scott, James C. 1998. Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to
Improve the Human Condition have Failed. New Haven: Yale University
Press
Sonnino, Sidney [1876] 1974. I Contadini di Sicilia. Florence: Vallecchi
Editore
Taylor, Michael 1982. Community, Anarchy and Liberty. New York:
Cambridge University Press, 1982
Tendler, Judith 1997. Good Government in the Tropics.Baltimore: The
Johns Hopkins University Press
Varese, Federico 2001. The Russian Mafia: Private Protection in a New
Market Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press

**********************************************************************
To join the list, send the message: join italian-studies YOUR NAME
to: [log in to unmask]
To send a message to the list, address it to:
[log in to unmask]
To leave the list, send the message: leave italian-studies
to: [log in to unmask]
In order to report problems or to contact the list's owners, write to:
[log in to unmask]
For further information, visit our web site:
http://www.jiscmail.ac.uk/lists/italian-studies.html

Top of Message | Previous Page | Permalink

JiscMail Tools


RSS Feeds and Sharing


Advanced Options


Archives

April 2024
March 2024
February 2024
January 2024
December 2023
November 2023
October 2023
September 2023
August 2023
July 2023
June 2023
May 2023
April 2023
March 2023
February 2023
January 2023
December 2022
November 2022
October 2022
September 2022
August 2022
July 2022
June 2022
May 2022
April 2022
March 2022
February 2022
January 2022
December 2021
November 2021
October 2021
September 2021
August 2021
July 2021
June 2021
May 2021
April 2021
March 2021
February 2021
January 2021
December 2020
November 2020
October 2020
September 2020
August 2020
July 2020
June 2020
May 2020
April 2020
March 2020
February 2020
January 2020
December 2019
November 2019
October 2019
September 2019
August 2019
July 2019
June 2019
May 2019
April 2019
March 2019
February 2019
January 2019
December 2018
November 2018
October 2018
September 2018
August 2018
July 2018
June 2018
May 2018
April 2018
March 2018
February 2018
January 2018
December 2017
November 2017
October 2017
September 2017
August 2017
July 2017
June 2017
May 2017
April 2017
March 2017
February 2017
January 2017
December 2016
November 2016
October 2016
September 2016
August 2016
July 2016
June 2016
May 2016
April 2016
March 2016
February 2016
January 2016
December 2015
November 2015
October 2015
September 2015
August 2015
July 2015
June 2015
May 2015
April 2015
March 2015
February 2015
January 2015
December 2014
November 2014
October 2014
September 2014
August 2014
July 2014
June 2014
May 2014
April 2014
March 2014
February 2014
January 2014
December 2013
November 2013
October 2013
September 2013
August 2013
July 2013
June 2013
May 2013
April 2013
March 2013
February 2013
January 2013
December 2012
November 2012
October 2012
September 2012
August 2012
July 2012
June 2012
May 2012
April 2012
March 2012
February 2012
January 2012
December 2011
November 2011
October 2011
September 2011
August 2011
July 2011
June 2011
May 2011
April 2011
March 2011
February 2011
January 2011
December 2010
November 2010
October 2010
September 2010
August 2010
July 2010
June 2010
May 2010
April 2010
March 2010
February 2010
January 2010
December 2009
November 2009
October 2009
September 2009
August 2009
July 2009
June 2009
May 2009
April 2009
March 2009
February 2009
January 2009
December 2008
November 2008
October 2008
September 2008
August 2008
July 2008
June 2008
May 2008
April 2008
March 2008
February 2008
January 2008
December 2007
November 2007
October 2007
September 2007
August 2007
July 2007
June 2007
May 2007
April 2007
March 2007
February 2007
January 2007
December 2006
November 2006
October 2006
September 2006
August 2006
July 2006
June 2006
May 2006
April 2006
March 2006
February 2006
January 2006
December 2005
November 2005
October 2005
September 2005
August 2005
July 2005
June 2005
May 2005
April 2005
March 2005
February 2005
January 2005
December 2004
November 2004
October 2004
September 2004
August 2004
July 2004
June 2004
May 2004
April 2004
March 2004
February 2004
January 2004
December 2003
November 2003
October 2003
September 2003
August 2003
July 2003
June 2003
May 2003
April 2003
March 2003
February 2003
January 2003
December 2002
November 2002
October 2002
September 2002
August 2002
July 2002
June 2002
May 2002
April 2002
March 2002
February 2002
January 2002
December 2001
November 2001
October 2001
September 2001
August 2001
July 2001
June 2001
May 2001
April 2001
March 2001
February 2001
January 2001
December 2000
November 2000
October 2000
September 2000
August 2000
July 2000
June 2000
May 2000
April 2000
March 2000
February 2000
January 2000
December 1999
November 1999
October 1999
September 1999
August 1999
July 1999
June 1999
May 1999
April 1999
March 1999
February 1999
January 1999
December 1998
November 1998
October 1998
September 1998
August 1998
July 1998
June 1998
May 1998
April 1998
March 1998
February 1998
January 1998
December 1997
November 1997
October 1997
September 1997
August 1997
July 1997
June 1997
May 1997
April 1997
March 1997
February 1997
January 1997
December 1996


JiscMail is a Jisc service.

View our service policies at https://www.jiscmail.ac.uk/policyandsecurity/ and Jisc's privacy policy at https://www.jisc.ac.uk/website/privacy-notice

For help and support help@jisc.ac.uk

Secured by F-Secure Anti-Virus CataList Email List Search Powered by the LISTSERV Email List Manager