JiscMail Logo
Email discussion lists for the UK Education and Research communities

Help for UTSG Archives


UTSG Archives

UTSG Archives


UTSG@JISCMAIL.AC.UK


View:

Message:

[

First

|

Previous

|

Next

|

Last

]

By Topic:

[

First

|

Previous

|

Next

|

Last

]

By Author:

[

First

|

Previous

|

Next

|

Last

]

Font:

Proportional Font

LISTSERV Archives

LISTSERV Archives

UTSG Home

UTSG Home

UTSG  2000

UTSG 2000

Options

Subscribe or Unsubscribe

Subscribe or Unsubscribe

Log In

Log In

Get Password

Get Password

Subject:

Bus lanes & Moore's Law revisited

From:

[log in to unmask]

Reply-To:

<[log in to unmask]>

Date:

Sat, 8 Jan 2000 12:52:59 +0100

Content-Type:

text/plain

Parts/Attachments:

Parts/Attachments

text/plain (264 lines)

I guess that since Kerry Wood posted this here (and for those who may not
have Kerry's notes in front of you I have (exceptionally) logged in the
whole thing below) it's cause comments and perhaps useful ideas and
reflections are in order. Let me have a shot, but first a word from our
sponsor:

Kerry, it is a splendid thing indeed to see so much good sense making its
way into halls of transport counsel (and of course better yet when they make
their way into transport practice). For a long time, these were for most
cities marginal ideas, so far out of the mainstream of what was perceived to
be possible and desirable that they never even began to get a hearing. How
rewarding it is, therefore, after a couple of decades to see such ideas
starting to shape the mainstream.  We still are a bit of a way from that
accomplishment of course, but it strikes me that we are now beginning to be
well on our way.  All it takes is more work, more imagination and more
examples on the ground which are just so extremely striking that they can no
longer be denied (thanks, Zurich, Curitiba and eventually hundreds of other
cities, mainly in Europe, which are starting to change the rules and our
perceptions of what works and what most evidently does not).

Observations on the draft:

1. "...speeding up ALL traffic by making public transport faster and more
efficient..."
I am afraid that a tremble at the hypothesis so stated, as I am sure you do.
But permit me to carry on for a moment on this.  The advantage of putting it
this way of course is that it pre-empts the cars-first crowd, by suggesting
to them that what's good for the system will also be good for them. That may
be cagey politics but it's dangerous and I think ultimately quite wrong.
Dangerous, because it may give them more rope to go out and make THEIR
traffic hustle along even faster, which of course gives all the other modes
the short end of the stick... once again. And wrong of course because as
Wood and others have abundantly pointed out, the only way to make any sense
out of the system is to render the environment steadily, each day a little
more, somewhere between unfriendly and inimical to the good old private car.
In the sustainable city, you will see the odd solo-driver car here and there
during the day, just like you see the old Spotted Owl, and it will set you
to wondering "Whatever is THAT doing HERE?"

2. "...raise bus lanes.."
Ouch. This strikes me like a first-generation "solution", for which one can
understand all the reasons and thinking behind it but which one still needs
to pop right into the dustbin. This is not to toss out the problem of lane
clearing, which I think can be solved (later), but it is to suggest that
anything more than a thick stripe of plastic paint or whatever is both
potentially dangerous and unfriendly to others out there on the street.
They also tend to be quite ugly, even threatening, and I do think that we
already have enough ugly and threatening things in most of our cities not to
consciously opt for more.

3. "...bus gate..."
broadly as above.


To conclude:  Bus lanes are a terrific way to start to organize thinking and
practice on sustainable transport in cities, because they are concrete, they
now come complete with a growing number of convincing demonstration sites
(meaning that you can just haul your politicos and traffic mavens over to a
selection of places so they can see for themselves.... perchance to dream),
because they do not require enormous gobs of hard earned taxpayer dollars,
and because it's something that any city can start to move toward, say,
beginning tomorrow morning. All you have to do is find a way to sell the
idea, and then, with proper preparation, it should simply sell itself.

A final wrinkle and observation: Think of bus lanes and all that goes with
them (including the SurfaceMetro concept, pace Curitiba) as today being
still in theory and in practice in very early stages of their evolution.
Say, the on-street equivalent of an  Apple II on your desk in 1977 and just
about everyone who passes asks you why ever would you waste your time with
that. Filing recipes?

Conclusion: Let's get together and see if we can apply Moore's Law to
transport in cities.  Wouldn't you say that 18 months is just about the
right amount of time to demonstrate that we too can double and half?  Might
we think about that together too?

Eric Britton

P.S. If I can have the author's permission, we would like to post his
completed article as the Essay of the Month on the @Access on the Web site
at http://www.ecoplan.org/access . The idea is to encourage both
distribution of leading edge thinking on these matters, as well as
discussion. The author would be in good company, if you check it out - the
present resident of that slot being Peter Drucker.

ecopl@n ___  technology, economy, society  ___
Le Frene, 8/10 rue Joseph Bara, 75006 Paris, France
[log in to unmask]     URL www.ecoplan.org
Tel: +331.4326.1323 Videoconference +331.4441.6340 (1-4)
Fax/voicemail hotline: In Europe +331 5301 2896
Fax/voicemail hotline: In North America +1 888 522 6419 (toll free)



>From Kerry Wood [[log in to unmask]] on 08/01/2000
I am in the middle of a paper on speeding up ALL traffic by making public
transport faster and more efficient. Here are some bits from it (sorry, it
has diagrams which get messy on e-mail)

ISTP data shows that cities with low car use have low overall transport
costs. (I have used their figures for operating cost of non-freight
transport)

For as long as the debate is about road building for cars, it is not so much
about improving transport as about how quickly it will get worse.

Huge figures for the cost of congestion are meaningless in a policy context
because there is no prospect of realizing the savings: Mogridge (1997)
refers to 'ghost city' traffic flows. They can also be used to support any
option, and so cannot discriminate between options.

It has been known since the Buchanan report (1963) that full motorisation is
impracticable in a large city - especially if that city has a high density.

Speeding up motor traffic is self-defeating in four ways:
* If the car-carrying capacity of the road is increased, the cost curve for
cars is flattened. The result is that some passengers switch from passenger
transport to car use. More cars quickly offset the savings and costs return
to their old level (the cost curve is very steep in congested traffic, so
mode switching does not have to be on a large scale). However, passenger
transport costs increase because there are fewer passengers: fares may rise,
the operator may take off some services, or the service may even close.
Higher costs encourage more passengers to switch to car use, so car costs
rise until they reach the new passenger transport costs. When the
readjustments are complete the point where the cost curves for passenger
transport and cars cross is at a higher cost than before the capacity
increase: the road 'improvement' has increased costs for everybody.
* Capacity increase in an urban area simply releases suppressed demand.
This accounts for the common observation, first made in the 1930s, that a
new urban highway does not reduce traffic on the old route (SACTRA 1994).
SACTRA's explanation is that new capacity induces new traffic on an
important scale, which is not allowed for in most transport modelling.
* Urban design effects. For example, good car mobility allows supermarkets
to drive local stores out of business, frustrating accessibility and needing
more mobility to meet the demand created
* Buses are slowed down in four ways. They have greater difficulty in
re-entering a faster traffic stream after a stop, or in crossing fast
traffic to reach a right turn lane; they consistently miss traffic lights
set to give motor traffic a 'green wave' through several junctions, because
of the need to stop for passengers; they suffer long delays at traffic
lights set to maximise traffic capacity by using long phases; and they often
follow a more circuitous route to pick up passengers.

Suppressed demand is usually a smaller economic problem than excess demand.
SACTRA (1999) studied the economic impacts of reducing traffic, and
concluded:
"The external costs arising from road transport provide a rationale for
traffic reduction insofar as it arises from the alignment of marginal
benefit with marginal social cost.  (7.125)
"..a more efficient allocation of resources might result from well?targeted
reduction measures. There is a strong case for correcting market failure
since marginal social costs appear to exceed marginal benefit on many
journeys." (7.126)

Reducing capacity also has little effect on speeds. Cairns and her
co-workers (1998) found 47 traffic reduction schemes where usable data was
available, with an average area-wide reduction of 25% of the capacity of the
altered streets. Crucially, they could not find any example of capacity
reduction causing 'traffic chaos,' beyond a short adjustment period (it will
be alright by Friday), even when there were catastrophic reductions due to
earthquakes.

Road building making the situation worse is called the Downs-Thomson effect.
Thomson (1977) describes the process like this:
"If the decision to use public or private transport is left to the free
choice of the individual commuter, an equilibrium will be reached in which
the overall attractiveness of the two systems is about equal, because if one
is faster, cheaper and more agreeable than the other there will be a shift
of passengers to it, rendering it more crowded while the other becomes less
so, until a position is reached where no?one on either system thinks there
is any advantage in changing to the other...
"Hence we derive one of the golden rules of urban transport: the quality of
peak?hour travel by car tends to equal that of public transport."

Studies of door-to-door travel speeds in several cities show that speeds on
public and private transport are remarkably similar, and studies of
household travel surveys show that about 15% of commuter cars are not used
every day: there is mode switching going on.

Zurich is one of several European cities that have pursued a policy of
improving public transport for some years. It is a particularly interesting
example because excellent results have been achieved at comparatively low
cost, with few subways and some surprisingly old vehicles. The head of VBZ,
the Zurich transport authority, claims:
"The only way to reduce traffic problems is to promote public transport
.

"Our strategy has been promoting public transport, reducing non-essential
car traffic, funneling traffic onto trunk roads, reducing parking provision
and encouraging pedestrians and cyclists."  (Heierli 1996)

Cost/modal split diagrams (following Mogridge) show that speeding up
passenger transport also speeds up cars EVEN IF SPACE IS TAKEN FROM CARS TO
MAKE ROOM FOR PASSENGER TRANSPORT. This is what has been done in Zurich, as
well as many other European cities. It seems to boost rather than depress
the economy.

ISTP data includes in-vehicle speeds for private and passenger transport for
a range of cities, as well as the proportion of journeys to work by car.
Plotting these gives a clear boundary line, which seems to represent the
Downs-Thomson effect: all the cities quoted by Mogridge are on on close to
this line.

Mogridge (1997) mentions sample calculations suggesting that in central
London average traffic speeds could be doubled by favouring passenger
transport: clearly this would being major commercial benefits. Trucks have
to be considered, but they do not necessarily need more road space - they
are usually only about 10% of a traffic stream.

A common assumption is that business people need car access, but what they
really need is good access. Heierli (1996) says:
"Zurich has... succeeded in giving its public transport operators the image
of modern companies with a clear customer focus, which... results in a very
positive image. The outcome of this is that there is no stigma attached to
travelling by tram in Zurich; indeed, anyone who does not use the tram tends
to be regarded as out of touch.
"Our politicians make regular use of public transport (not just at election
times) and leading figures from economic and academic life would not
consider commuting in any other way."




References
Buchanan, C (1963)  Traffic in Towns. London: HMSO
Cairns, S; Hass?Klau, C and Goodwin, P (1998) Traffic impact of highway
capacity reductions: assessment of the evidence. London: Landor.
Heierli, R (1996)  European Lecture: Public transport in Zurich.  Proc Instn
Civil Engineers, Transport 117, November Mogridge, MJH (1997) The
self?defeating nature of urban road capacity policy. Transport Policy 4 (1)
pp 5?23 Thomson, JM (1977) Great cities and their traffic. London: Gollancz.
Quoted in Mogridge (1997)



I like the idea of running bus lanes in the 'wrong' direction to keep cars
out of the lane. Thanks Lake.
Another approach is to raise bus lanes about 80-120 mm above the general
traffic lanes (or about 150 mm with a beveled kerb), so that motor vehicles
can use them at low speed in emergency, but not just to save a few seconds.
Brussels uses a thing like a painted broken line, but the 'paint' is
concrete and 100 mm high.
A good design for a 'bus gate' to keep other traffic out of a bus lane is a
narrow section of road, between kerbs, with a level surface where the bus
wheels go but a dip where the narrower car wheels go. It doesn't matter if
the inner wheels on the back axle of the bus are unsupported.  The dip can
be enough to slow cars down, or deep enough to stop them, and a ridge (low
enough to clear the bus differential) stops them from going over the dip too
fast for their wheels to drop in. The trouble is that it is comparatively
expensive, because the dip needs separate drainage.


--
Kerry Wood  MICE  MIPENZ  MCIT
Transport Consultant
1 McFarlane Street, Wellington 6001, New Zealand
Phone + 64  4  971 5549





%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%

Top of Message | Previous Page | Permalink

JiscMail Tools


RSS Feeds and Sharing


Advanced Options


Archives

April 2024
March 2024
February 2024
January 2024
December 2023
November 2023
October 2023
September 2023
August 2023
July 2023
June 2023
May 2023
April 2023
March 2023
February 2023
January 2023
December 2022
November 2022
October 2022
September 2022
August 2022
July 2022
June 2022
May 2022
April 2022
March 2022
February 2022
January 2022
December 2021
November 2021
October 2021
September 2021
August 2021
July 2021
June 2021
May 2021
April 2021
March 2021
February 2021
January 2021
December 2020
November 2020
October 2020
September 2020
August 2020
July 2020
June 2020
May 2020
April 2020
March 2020
February 2020
January 2020
December 2019
November 2019
October 2019
September 2019
August 2019
July 2019
June 2019
May 2019
April 2019
March 2019
February 2019
January 2019
December 2018
November 2018
October 2018
September 2018
August 2018
July 2018
June 2018
May 2018
April 2018
March 2018
February 2018
January 2018
December 2017
November 2017
October 2017
September 2017
August 2017
July 2017
June 2017
May 2017
April 2017
March 2017
February 2017
January 2017
December 2016
November 2016
October 2016
September 2016
August 2016
July 2016
June 2016
May 2016
April 2016
March 2016
February 2016
January 2016
December 2015
November 2015
October 2015
September 2015
August 2015
July 2015
June 2015
May 2015
April 2015
March 2015
February 2015
January 2015
December 2014
November 2014
October 2014
September 2014
August 2014
July 2014
June 2014
May 2014
April 2014
March 2014
February 2014
January 2014
December 2013
November 2013
October 2013
September 2013
August 2013
July 2013
June 2013
May 2013
April 2013
March 2013
February 2013
January 2013
December 2012
November 2012
October 2012
September 2012
August 2012
July 2012
June 2012
May 2012
April 2012
March 2012
February 2012
January 2012
December 2011
November 2011
October 2011
September 2011
August 2011
July 2011
June 2011
May 2011
April 2011
March 2011
February 2011
January 2011
December 2010
November 2010
October 2010
September 2010
August 2010
July 2010
June 2010
May 2010
April 2010
March 2010
February 2010
January 2010
December 2009
November 2009
October 2009
September 2009
August 2009
July 2009
June 2009
May 2009
April 2009
March 2009
February 2009
January 2009
December 2008
November 2008
October 2008
September 2008
August 2008
July 2008
June 2008
May 2008
April 2008
March 2008
February 2008
January 2008
December 2007
November 2007
October 2007
September 2007
August 2007
July 2007
June 2007
May 2007
April 2007
March 2007
February 2007
January 2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
2002
2001
2000
1999
1998


JiscMail is a Jisc service.

View our service policies at https://www.jiscmail.ac.uk/policyandsecurity/ and Jisc's privacy policy at https://www.jisc.ac.uk/website/privacy-notice

For help and support help@jisc.ac.uk

Secured by F-Secure Anti-Virus CataList Email List Search Powered by the LISTSERV Email List Manager